© Copyright
JASSS
Guido Fioretti
(2001)
Information Structure and Behaviour of a Textile
Industrial District
Journal of Artificial Societies and Social
Simulation vol. 4, no.
4
<http://www.soc.surrey.ac.uk/JASSS/4/4/1.html>
To cite articles published in the Journal of Artificial
Societies and Social Simulation, please reference the above information and
include paragraph numbers if necessary
Received: 5-Feb-01
Accepted: 15-Aug-01
Published: 31-Oct-01
Abstract
- This article presents a model of the structure of the information flows
that underlie the creation of production chains between thousands of small
textile firms located in Prato, central Italy. Contrary to most textile
industry of western Europe and north America, Prato did not die out once
average salaries in the region rose towards the world's highest. The reason is
that Prato was able to switch from a competitive advantage based on low prices
to a competitive advantage based on the aesthetical features and variety of
textiles. Analysis of the structure of production chains can explain the
performance of this distributed production system throughout its evolution.
The model reconstructs interactions of ten types of Pratese firms from 1946 to
1993 on a scale of 1:1.
- Keywords:
- Prato, Industrial Districts, Distributed Intelligence
Introduction
- 1.1
- It often happens that firms operating in the same industry are also
geographically clustered, but, in many or possibly most cases, physical
proximity does not affect firms' individualistic behaviour. On the contrary,
in some cases firms that are close to one another and operate in the same
industry entertain complex and variable relationships of competition and
collaboration with one another, ranging from formal subcontracting to informal
communications that foster innovation and entrepreneurship. Alfred Marshall
first pointed to the peculiar "industrial atmosphere" of certain clusters,
pointing to Sheffield's cutlery industry in the nineteenth century as a
prototypical example of this peculiar industrial organisation (Marshall,
1920). Following Marshall, industrial clusters where the structure of
interactions matters for aggregate outcome are called industrial
districts.
- 1.2
- Until the last two decades of the twentieth century, mass production of
standardised goods generally called for large, vertically integrated Fordist
firms. Consequently, common wisdom among economists was that economic
development necessarily follows a path that leads to ever larger firms.
According to the view prevailing at that time, industrial districts can only
be found in the early stages of economic development.
- 1.3
- However, just in the typically Fordist decades after World War II a large
part of Italy was providing an exception to this paradigm. Giacomo Becattini
first noted that, besides the heavy industrialised North-West and the
depressed South, a "third Italy" was growing in the Center-North and
North-East areas, one which based economic development on a huge number of
small, family-owned firms (Becattini
1969, Becattini
1975). Becattini based his considerations on Tuscany, particularly on a
textile district located in Prato, near Florence. With its thousands of firms,
mostly very small and specialised in a single production phase, Prato became
the prototypical Italianate industrial district.
- 1.4
- Industrial districts became fashionable but, possibly, in the wrong way.
Less than twenty years after their discovery, some scholars had to remark that
during the 1980s industrial districts had become an opposite, equally
arbitrary view of economic development based on small-scale capitalism,
collaboration and harmony (Amin and Robins
1990; Amin and
Thrift 1992). Sharing their critical but constructive attitude, several
field studies questioned the realism of this idealised picture. On the one
hand, a number of empirical investigations highlighted the importance of
hierarchical structures within industrial districts, in Italy and elsewhere
(Scott 1992;
Gray, Golob,
Markusen and Park 1998; Lazerson and
Lorenzoni 1999; Rabellotti and
Schmitz 1999). On the other hand, other authors pointed to low wages,
workers exploitation and poor environmental controls in small firms as a key
determinant for the economic success of industrial districts (Harrison
1994; De Cecco
2000) while, at least in Italy, the conflict-composing force of family
ties is fading away (Pietrobelli
1998).
- 1.5
- In short, industrial districts are interesting because they seem to be an
instance of the idea that "the whole is more than the sum of its parts".
However, one may suspect that a grim reality of poverty and exploitation hides
behind the facade. Prato is an ideal place to assess the relative weight of
these interpretations, and not only because it is the very place that
initiated modern theorising on industrial districts.
- 1.6
- In Prato, a textile manufacturing tradition goes back to the Middle Ages.
Industrialisation came at the end of the nineteenth century, when a few large
woollen mills joined a long-standing craft tradition of independent weavers
and warpers. Prato maintained this structure until the end of World War II:
until this time, one cannot speak of a Marshallian industrial district with
its "industrial atmosphere".
- 1.7
- The economic crisis ensuing the end of World War II was the event that
marked the beginning of the most famous Italian industrial districts (Cioni 1997). In
a situation of extreme poverty, with woollen mills shutting down or resizing
their productive capacity, young members of large extended families devoted to
commerce or agriculture started to integrate their income with some irregular
work at the loom, for which they could eventually mobilise their whole family
just as they used to do at harvest times. Another source of independent firms
was provided directly by the large woollen mills, particularly during the 1949
crisis. Simply, managers offered workers the options of either buying or
renting looms or other machinery and being contracted at demand peaks, or
being fired. Many workers, particularly those who could set a large family to
work, found it a good deal.
- 1.8
- In both cases, self-exploitation of one's own family members was
determinant for the profitability of these minuscule firms. Actually, many
among the many thousands of independent firms in the district should be rather
called "precarious workers".[1] Given the
importance of self-exploitation for the Pratese economy, my question is: What
happened in the subsequent decades, when salaries rose and people could find
better jobs? Why does Prato still exist as an industrial district?
- 1.9
- A first answer is that, due to massive clandestine immigration, Prato can
still rely on a cheap labour force. Exploitation and self-exploitation never
ended, and possibly increased because nowadays many workers do not have any
legal right whatsoever, not even permission to stay in Italy. Interestingly,
most foreign immigrants are Chineses coming from the Zhejiang province, where
a socks and stockings district based on small family firms is flourishing on
similar lines as in Prato (Wang, Zhu and Tong
2001).
- 1.10
- Clearly, quantifying clandestine immigration is impossible if one only
looks at official statistics. However, a rough estimate can be provided by
Caritas, the Catholic agency for the poor. In fact, in 1995 and 1998
the State offered legalisation to clandestine immigrants who could demonstrate
that they had been living and working in Italy for a certain number of years.
Obviously, such a certification could not be provided by the firms for which
these people worked illegally. On the contrary, Caritas could provide
such a certification if a clandestine immigrate had registered early enough
with it. Since 1988, Pratese Caritas has collected data on clandestine
immigrants who ask to be registered in their files, as well as the number of
those who made use of the two legalisations in 1995 and 1998.
- 1.11
- Figure 1 shows
clandestine immigrants according to Caritas data (red line), net of
legalisations in 1995 and 1998. Furthermore, official statistics on foreign
residents have been added (blue line).
|
Figure 1. The red line shows clandestine immigrants in Prato
according to Caritas files, net of legalisations in 1995 and 1998 (Caritas
2000). Although Caritas started to collect data in 1988, no
clandestine was recorded in 1988 and 1989. The blue line shows foreign
residents in the Prato province, 1995 to 1999 (ISTAT
2000). Foreign residents in the previous years have been guessed by
subtracting from foreign residents in 1995 the net inflow to Prato from
abroad (ISTAT
1990-1994). Clearly, this estimate is reliable only to the extent
that net flows from abroad are constituted by foreign citizens, that net
flows of foreign citizens between Prato and other Italian provinces are
negligible, and that among foreigners deaths compensate births.
|
- 1.12
- Clearly, only a fraction of illegal workers resorts to Caritas so
the above is likely to be a cautious estimate, particularly for early years
when rumours about the possibility of legalisations were not widespread and
the role of Caritas was not clear. Even with these data, clandestine
immigrants are about one third of legally resident foreigners, which is
sufficient to have an impact on real labour costs. This impression is
confirmed by data on the inspections carried out by the Italian agency for
labour safety (INPS), where Prato stays on top of illegal labour in Tuscany
(Baccini,
Castellucci, Mori and Vasta 2001).
- 1.13
- However, availability of cheap labour is not sufficient to explain Prato's
puzzle. After all, moving a plant or subcontracting abroad is easier than
relying on clandestine workers whose presence exposes firms to rackets of any
sort. If self-exploitation would be the only determinant of Prato's economic
success, then why not just move production abroad when labour cost increases?
Most textile districts in Western Europe and North America did so. Why did not
Prato?
- 1.14
- Actually, there has been a time where this seemed to be Prato's fate as
well. As we have seen, the district originated in the early 1950s, gained
momentum at the beginning of the 1960s and continued to expand throughout the
1960s and 1970s. However, at the beginning of the 1980s a deep crisis struck
Prato. Experts had good reason to claim that textile production was no longer
feasible in a region where income had been raised to the world's highest
standards, and that textile production would move away. Figure 2 illustrates this
development in terms of production plants and number of workers (official
statistics).
- 1.15
- Surprisingly, the predictions were not fulfilled. Contrary to all
expectations, Prato managed to recover during the 1990s. Recovery is not
evident from figures 2a and 2b, which only point to industry concentration in
the first half of the 1990s, but it is evident to all local operators (Balestri and
Toccafondi 1994, Balestri and
Toccafondi 1995).
- 1.16
- However, Prato is now a very different district from the one that existed
in the 1960s and 1970s. It is less typical a district, both because some
concentration did take place and because it is no longer a self-contained
productive area. Most importantly, Prato switched from a competitive advantage
based on price to a competitive advantage based on taste and product variety:
I claim that here lies the reason of its unexpected recovery.
- 1.17
- Since these qualities are deeply embedded in the local culture, workers
had to move from low-wage countries to Prato instead of plants moving from
Prato to low-wage countries. Note that, from this point of view, Prato is
actually even more a Marshallian district today than it used to be in the
1960s and 1970s. Today more than ever, its competitive advantage relies on
local culture, tradition or, to speak in Marshall's terms, "atmosphere".
- 1.18
- This article aims to disentangle the role of price-based competitive
advantage from variety-based competitive advantage, from the end of World War
II to the beginning of the recovery of the 1990s. It does so by means of a
model of interacting firms, in the conviction that different sources of
competitive advantage reflect different business relationships. In particular,
Section 2 explains
the influence of single production phases on different sources of competitive
advantage, Section 3 illustrates the
structure of information flows within the district, and Section 4 presents the model.
Finally, Section 5
illustrates the results of the model and Section 6 concludes.
From Price Flexibility to feature flexibility
- 2.1
- Traditionally, Prato used to produce low-quality, low-price textiles out
of regenerated wool. Regenerated wool is obtained from used clothes and
woollen rags of almost any sort, after a series of chemical and mechanical
processes that yield less resistant, rougher fabrics than virgin wool.
- 2.2
- Of the two spinning methods - carded spinning and combed spinning - only
the first can be used with regenerated wool. However, identifying carded
fabrics with lower-quality fabrics would be a mistake, since quality rather
depends on raw materials and processing details. Today, wool regeneration has
almost disappeared from Prato, average quality is much higher than it used to
be, but still, for historical reasons, most Pratese firms are focused on
carded fabrics.
- 2.3
- Figure 3
illustrates a general scheme of the production process to be found in Prato
(Avigdor
1961). Wool (either virgin or regenerated) must be spun (either carded or
combed), warped and then woven. Dyeing can either take place before spinning,
or between spinning and warping, or after weaving. Finally, fabrics receive a
final touch with finishing operations. Since technical innovations either
concern machinery or details that at this level of generality do not show up,
we can safely assume that this scheme did not change.
|
Figure 3. A scheme of the production process to be found in
Prato, rough enough to be considered constant over time. Dyeing can
either take place before spinning, or before warping, or just before
finishing operations. |
- 2.4
- Throughout the "Golden Age" of the 1960s and 1970s and well into the
1980s, most Pratese firms relied on regenerated wool, low quality and low
price. With its huge number of small firms doing the same things, the district
worked nearly like a textbook competitive economy where profits tend to zero.
- 2.5
- For many years, the district organisation discouraged technological
innovation (Bertini and Forlai
1989). On the one hand textile technology poses very low barriers to
entry, because if the only difference between current generation looms and
previous-generation looms is speed, then one can easily enter the market by
purchasing a second-hand loom and working harder than competitors. On the
other hand, once a worker has become independent, dedicated skills, personal
pride and, most importantly, a lack of alternative jobs that are not related
to the textile industry and move countercyclically to its ups and downs, erect
terrible barriers to exit. Thus, investment in technological excellence was
discouraged, since if a firm did that, it had to face price competition by a
number of craftsmen in despair.
- 2.6
- While the above is absolutely true for the first stages of the production
process, it becomes the less true the further we move towards the final
product (Aiazzi,
Baussola, Corsini, Ganugi and Langianni 1997). Rags are all alike and
weaving is all alike as well, but dyeing and, to a greater extent, finishing
offers a wider range of possibilities to differentiate products. Particularly
during the 1990s, the range of finishing operations increased enormously,
offering tremendous possibilities for differentiating final products (Bonafé, Giusti,
Limberti, Ponzecchi, Romagnoli and Terenzi 1999).
- 2.7
- Building on a sense of aesthetical inventiveness within a classical taste
that is typical of Tuscany, Pratese firms aimed to differentiate final
products. Quantitative estimates do not exist, but according to the Prato
industrialists' union's chief researcher, Andrea Balestri (2000),
product differentiation started in the 1970s, accelerated in the 1980s and has
continued to grow exponentially ever since.
- 2.8
- According to a survey carried out among customers in 1990, Prato is basing
its competitive advantage on its ability to provide anything a buyer may
request, in a reasonable time, in lots of any size and with great creativity
and taste (Balestri and
Toccafondi 1991). Low price comes last.
- 2.9
- Thus, by looking at firms that operate at different levels of the
productive process we can distinguish price-based competitive advantage from
variety-based competitive advantage. In both cases, the district attains
flexibility by means of massive interactions of a huge number of firms.
However, in the first case interactions take place pretty much in the way
neoclassical economics describes them, so the district attains price
flexibility. In contrast, in the second case interactions serve the
purpose of stimulating the ability to innovate by creating fabrics with novel
features (Lane and
Maxfield 1996; Maskell 2000).
I call this feature flexibility.
- 2.10
- This is the key observation for building the model that will be presented
in the following section, which aims to assess the relative importance of
price flexibility and feature flexibility. Notably, both price flexibility and
feature flexibility run contrary to the prescription of establishing stable
inter-firm relationships in order to attain higher qualitative standards.
- 2.11
- This is a widespread trend today. Originating from observation of the
superior performance of the Toyota manufacturing system in the 1980s, it
rapidly diffused across industries and countries. Allegedly, risk-sharing and
joint product development are important in order to enhance quality.
- 2.12
- Although it was conceived as a means to manage relationships between a
large corporation and its main subcontractors, the practice of relying on
long-term collaboration bears on industrial districts as well, particularly if
they rely on high-quality products (Nuti and Cainelli
1996). Prato is relying more on variety than qualitative excellence;
nonetheless, quality is a much-debated issue among local operators.
Traditionally, widespread subcontracting poses the following two problems with
respect to quality standards:
- Poor constancy of whatever quality level is requested by the customer,
since a single customer may receive lots that have been processed by
different firms;
- Free-riding, if poor quality on a production phase reduces the costs of
the firm that carries it out but increases the costs of the firm that
carries out the subsequent phase (Bertini and
Forlai 1989).
- 2.13
- In order to overcome these problems, some scholars are pleading for more
stable customer-supplier relationships according to the Toyota model (Ciappei and Neri
1998). However, the local chamber of commerce is attempting to pursue an
alternative strategy, based on a quality certification that entails checks of
all steps of the production process across different firms (Baldini and Tesi
1996). According to this view, quality certification by a State agency
could improve quality without impairing the flexibility upon which Prato based
its competitive advantage.
- 2.14
- Lack of data forces the model presented here to stop at the very beginning
of the 1990s. Up to that time, increasing stability of customer-supplier
relationships can be assumed not to be a relevant issue in Prato; however, it
might undermine the application of this model to a subsequent period.
The Structure of Information Flows
- 3.1
- The striking feature of industrial districts is that their macroscopic
behaviour exhibits features that its component firms do not have, since they
derive from the structure of interactions between component firms.
Differently from most economic theory and practice, the macroscopic behaviour
of industrial districts cannot be derived from summation of the behaviours of
single firms.
- 3.2
- If industrial districts are organisms rather than collections of isolated
agents, then it is quite natural to stress their similarity with
self-organising systems in physics and biology (Biggiero
2001). Particularly, brains are a very interesting class of
self-organising systems since distributed memory and knowledge arise out of
the structure of interactions between neurones. Thus, several authors have
pointed to the possibility of highlighting the "collective mind" of a district
by viewing it as a self-organising system (Rullani 1993;
Grandinetti
and Rullani 1994; Lombardi
2000, Lombardi
2001).
- 3.3
- This idea does make sense but - at least in respect of Prato - it needs
some qualification. Self-organisation may take place in systems that are
constituted by a large number of interacting parts, if patterns of
interactions are such that a macroscopic input is able to trigger the
formation of microscopic structures. In physics, the simplest examples of a
self-organising system are Bénard cells (Nicolis and
Prigogine 1977, Nicolis and
Prigogine 1989; Haken 1983, Haken 1987): if
one heats a pan filled with water from below, one observes the formation of
cells where water circulates from the heated bottom to the cool surface and
back. Interestingly, this is a microscopic structure that has been created by
a macroscopic input (the heat), not by microscopic command by single water
molecules. In biology, life itself is a self-organising system (Varela 1979; Rosen 1991),
since it consists of an organism's ability to re-produce the code and
conditions that generated itself. In essence, life is a logical circuit at the
microscopic level that is supported by macroscopic flows of matter and energy.
Finally, distributed, self-organising memories in human brains and artificial
neural nets are based on information circuits (Kohonen 1989).
The idea of a distributed memory is that information is not stored in any
particular neurone, but in the circuits where it flows within the system. Just
like any self-organising system, a distributed memory is made by a net of
microscopic links that can form themselves because of macroscopic conditions
in terms of blood flows or electrical current, in the case of artificial
neural nets.
- 3.4
- Strictly speaking, the idea of circuit, or feed-back, is not necessary in
order to have self-organisation. In fact, one could think of a system where
macroscopic stimuli trigger the generation of stars, or hierarchies, or any
other structure. For instance, von Foerster's famous example of a number of
little magnets that join into complex architectures is one where
self-organisation does not produce circuits (von Foerster
1982). However, from the above discussion it is clear that self-organising
systems where circuits arise are by far the most interesting ones, to the
point that self-organisation is generally thought of in connection with this
structure.
- 3.5
- Admittedly, viewing an industrial district as a self-organising system is
an intriguing idea. It means that each particular district has certain ways of
organising information flows that make it responsive to particular patterns of
demand or to particular technologies. However, a district that is able to form
stable information circuits would be one that has a collective behaviour of
which its component firms are not even conscious.
- 3.6
- Let us examine this case more carefully. A textile district that behaves
like that would be one where a multitude of small producers weave and warp
according to individual convenience, until fabrics come out that nobody
designed, nobody ordered but, miraculously, in the end somebody buys. Prato is
not like that, and I wonder if any district has ever been. Nonetheless,
certain forms of self-organisation do take place.
- 3.7
- In Prato, technical information, financial information and commercial
information flow according to very different patterns. Information regarding
technical innovations cannot be kept secret in Prato. Frequent subcontracting,
workers' mobility and the very fact that the technical innovations made in
Prato are incremental and can be easily adopted, are all factors that make
technical information spread very rapidly throughout the district. We can
think of irregular and provisional information structures of any kind,
including circuits, though possibly not stable enough to characterise the
macroscopic behaviour of the district. As regards financial information,
little or nothing is known. We know that family ties are important for
financing the smallest firms, we know that local credit institutes have
specific acquaintances and knowledge and we suspect that firm-to-firm loans
take place as well, but we have no information concerning the structure of all
these loans. However, we know the structure of commercial information.
Commercial information flows according to a pattern that corresponds to the
organisation of production in the district.
- 3.8
- In Prato, production is organised by a special class of agents, herein
called the middlemen (Bertini and Forlai
1989). A middleman can either be one of the large woollen mills, or a much
smaller firm eventually composed only of a manager, a secretary and a
telephone.[2] Contrary to
many other Pratese firms, middlemen have entrepreneurial spirit, make
strategic plans and are acquainted with the fashion industry.
- 3.9
- Whoever wants to buy in Prato, asks a middleman. If the order exceeds its
productive capacity, the middleman calls several small firms in order to carry
out specific production phases. Wares do not even need to pass physically
through the middleman's workshop, but the sequencing of operations is up to
the middleman.
- 3.10
- For a middleman, nothing is more crucial than that the identity of the
final buyer remains secret to the firms that he contracts. Otherwise, these
firms could possibly sell directly to the final buyer, or become middlemen
themselves. Obviously, this does not amount to claiming that middlemen do not
rely on communication, organisation and networking skills. However, keeping
the secrecy of private information is part of their job.
- 3.11
- If a firm that has been contracted by a middleman is not able to fulfil
the whole order with its productive capacity, it will contract another firm in
its turn. Thus, the contracted firm takes the middleman role with respect to
the firm that it contracts in its turn. This means that, at least in
principle, the information structure of subcontracting can repeat itself over
and over, like a fractal.
- 3.12
- Clearly, this structure of information flows does not produce information
circuits. It is a hierarchical information structure, where middlemen have the
power to direct information flows. However, note that at the lowest levels
this structure in not a single-hierarchy but rather a multi-hierarchy, since
it may happen that firm A contracts firm B and, at a later time, firm B
contracts firm A. In this sense, but only in this sense, it can be
claimed that reciprocity and collaboration are widespread in the district.
The Model
- 4.1
- The model aims to reconstruct the structure of business relationships
between Pratese firms throughout the evolution of the industrial district,
looking for a connection between the structure of business relationships and
the historical performance of the district as it was outlined in the
introduction. Clearly, the extent to which this can be done depends on the
amount of information that we have regarding business relationships within the
district.
- 4.2
- Although we know the structure of subcontracting, we do not have any data
concerning exchanges between firms within the district, either in money terms
or in physical magnitude. Similarly, data concerning the size of firms are
either fragmentary or too aggregate. The only disaggregated data about the
number of firms operating in 56 distinct production phases from 1946 to 1993,
was collected by Luciana Lazzeretti and Dimitri Storai (Lazzeretti and
Storai 1999). Unfortunately, the numerical content of this database is not
accessible, although a visual guess of the graphs entailed in the this
publication could be made.
- 4.3
- Thus, a very crude assumption has to be made in order to let a model run.
The assumption is that small firms process smaller lots than large firms, and
that firm size and lot size are perfectly related. If this assumption holds,
then the number of orders that firms place on one another is independent of
their size.
- 4.4
- Furthermore, in order to keep the model tractable, only 10 out of the 56
types of firms considered by Lazzeretti and Storai have been included in the
model. Firstly, firms that do not participate in the production processes
illustrated in figure 3 have been excluded.
Secondly, in order to curb the impact of the above assumption on lot sizes
compensating firm size, large woollen mills that occasionally act as middlemen
have been excluded as well. Finally, firms showing the most diverse population
dynamics have been selected in order not to have redundant information.
Ultimately, the ten types of firms that have been considered are: Traders of
Raw Materials, Rag Collectors, Carded Spinners, Combed Spinners, Warpers,
Weavers, Dyeing Plants, Finishers, Traders of Finished Products and Middlemen.
- 4.5
- Finally, since we neither know the geographical locations of firms nor the
informal networks of entrepreneurs, we cannot reproduce preferential
interactions between firms. Thus, firms can only be distributed uniformly in a
space that represents acquaintance proximity.
- 4.6
- To summarise, lack of data and computational complexity impose the
following limitations on the model:
- The number of firms is known imprecisely;
- One has to assume that firm size and lot size are related;
- Only a subset of types of firms has been included in the model;
- Acquaintances and preferential relationships are not known.
- 4.7
- Of the above limitations, (1) is the least serious and (2) the most
serious, but (3) and (4) affect the outcome as well. Unfortunately, there is
no way to test for their influence on the model except from ex post
observation of its results. However, one should keep in mind that this
model was not conceived in order to make numerical forecasts but in order to
better understand the historical performance of the district.
- 4.8
- The model reproduces the information structure described in Section 3.
Firms are represented by coloured squares on a black display. Firms move on
the display, forming production chains that appear as multi-coloured stripes.
Figure 4
illustrates the correspondence between firm type and the colour of the square
that represents it. Figure 5 shows a typical
simulation step, with isolated firms and production chains.
|
Figure 4. Correspondence between colours and types of firms.
Whenever possible, warm, pale colours have been used to represent early
stages of the production process, cool, dark colours to represent end
stages. |
|
Figure 5. A typical simulation step, chosen from the final
part of the time period in order to have a large number of firms and
production chains of different shapes. This picture stems from a run of
the 1:10 model. |
- 4.9
- Firms numbers are available in 1:1, 1:2 and 1:10 scale. Since scaling
affects the results of the model, 1:1 scaling should be used in order to
derive realistic values. However, 1:10 scaling makes sense if we want to see a
clear picture of the formation of production chains. The advantages and
drawbacks of 1:2 scaling lie in between.
- 4.10
- Each year is subdivided into steps. At each step, firms interact. In order
to obtain smooth results, the number of interactions should be approximately
the same every year. However, since the number of firms is different every
year, the number of steps should not be the same every year. Consequently, the
number of steps is found by requiring that the product of the number of steps
and the number of firms is constant.
- 4.11
- At each step, all firms except middlemen make a random move in the area.
In particular, traders of finished products look for a middleman. As soon as
they detect a middleman in their watching range, and after checking that at
least one of its four sides is free, they move there and place an order.
Theoretically, the fact that middlemen can only create up to four production
chains at a time is an unjustified assumption. In practice, on an average of
ten simulations the fraction of times where a middleman built four chains was
less than 0.2%, so if five or more chains could be built, the results would
not change much.
- 4.12
- At this point, the middleman looks around for suitable firms in order to
build a production chain. Middlemen arrange firms into sequences that respect
the technological constraints illustrated in figure 3 (Avigdor 1961).
Given the 10 types of firms that we are considering, technological constraints
restrict the set of possibilities to the 11 production chains illustrated in
figure 6.
|
Figure 6. The eleven production chains that can be
constructed with the ten given types of firms. Abbreviations are as
follows: TRM = Trader Raw Materials; RC = Rags Collector; CaS = Carded
Spinning; CoS = Combed Spinning; Wa = Warper; We = Weaver; DP = Dyeing
Plant; F = Finisher; TFP = Trader Finished Products. Middlemen are not
part of production chains, but rather organise them.
|
- 4.13
- Production chains may vary from one another because some production
factors can be either produced within the district or purchased outside,
because spinning can be either carded or combed, and because dyeing can take
place at different production stages. Nonetheless, all production chains must
begin with a trader of finished products and end with a trader of raw
materials.
- 4.14
- Figure 7
illustrates production chains that vary from one another because of the
sequencing of operations, because they make use of carded or combed spinning,
and because intermediate products are purchased outside the district. In this
latter case, production chains are shorter.
|
Figure 7. Four examples of production chains. Chain A
consists of buying wool, combed spinning, dyeing, warping, weaving,
finishing and selling fabrics. Chain B differs from chain A because it
makes use of carded spinning, rather than combed spinning. Chain C
differs from chain B only because dyeing takes place at a later stage.
Finally, chain D differs from chain C because yarn is purchased outside
the district. |
- 4.15
- In order to arrange a production chain, a middleman looks first for a firm
that can be added to a trader of finished products, that must be a finisher
according to figure 6. As soon as the
middleman has found a finisher, he attaches it to the trader of finished
products. Then the middleman looks for a firm that can be added to the
finisher, that according to figure 6 can either be a
weaver or a dyeing plant. And so on, until a trader of raw materials is found
and the production chain has been completed.
- 4.16
- Thus, selection of one of the eleven possible production chains depends on
which firms are nearest to the middleman. Implicitly, this model assumes that
the empirically given number of firms subsumes all microeconomic variables
that determine exchanges. In other words, it assumes economic equilibrium
through firms' reproduction and selection and reconstructs the structure of
information flows for any given equilibrium state.
- 4.17
- At the end of each step, all production chains are destroyed and component
firms are set free. However, if the trader of finished products remains close
enough to the middleman, the next step it will prompt the construction of a
production chain attached at the same side of the same middleman. Thus, when
looking at the simulation one may have the impression that some production
chains stay there for quite a long time.
- 4.18
- However, the reconstructed chain is not necessarily identical with the
previous one. Firstly, because component firms may have changed even if their
type did not. Secondly, because dyeing plants can be placed at different
points of a production chain. In this latter case, we may see a production
chain staying there except for some coloured squares exchanging their places.
- 4.19
- The model can be downloaded, used and distributed according to the terms
of the GNU public license. It is available in zip and tar.gz
compression.
- 4.20
- Even without running the model, construction and destruction of production
chains can be seen in a movie of the last four simulation years (Animation 1).
Production chains occasionally take weird shapes in order to avoid locations
where other firms are present without impairing the results of the simulation.
Consider that since the simulation refers to information exchange, not
production, it is not unrealistic to see many idle firms at a time.
|
Animation 1. [To restart the animation, click on the image
and select Reload from the right button menu]
|
- 4.21
- Once the model is set up, our task is that of identifying magnitudes that
link the structure of information flows to price flexibility and feature
flexibility. The next section derives a few indicators of Prato information
structure and compares them with the historical development of this industrial
district.
The Indicators
- 5.1
- Indicators should reflect the flexibility of the district, in terms of
price as well as in terms of the qualitative features of fabrics. Both price
and feature flexibility depend on the availability of a wide range of
possibilities for building production chains. In fact, the availability of a
large number of firms in a large number of types enables middlemen to change
the firms that they contract with frequently.
- 5.2
- Thus, we can measure flexibility by means of an index of the variability
of the production chains that are built in the district. The more variable
production chains are, the more flexible is the district both in terms of
price and features of its products.
- 5.3
- However, if the number of types of firms is given and the number of firms
is increasing, then an increasing number of firms will be arranged into
identical production chains at any given point in time. This results in
increasing parallelism of information processing, meaning that at each step
there will be several identical production chains.
- 5.4
- Although a certain degree of parallelism may contribute to the flexibility
of the district, too high a parallelism indicates that the overall volume of
orders is large enough for production to be organised more efficiently by
larger firms. Thus, it is convenient to use parallelism as a second indicator
of the overall performance of the district.
- 5.5
- Variability is computed as follows. At each time step, the program records
which production chains are built and to which side of which middleman they
are attached. During each year, the program compares the chains that are built
in the current step with the chains that were built in the previous step.
Every time that a production chain is found attached to the same side of the
same middleman as in the previous step, a variable constancy is
incremented. Subsequently, a degreeOfVariability is defined as one
minus the ratio of constancy to the number of chains that have been
built during the current step. A summedDegreeOfVariability sums the
degreeOfVariability over a year. Finally, variability during one year
is obtained by dividing summedDegreeOfVariability by the number of
steps in that year.
- 5.6
- Parallelism is computed as follows. At each time step, the program records
which production chains are built. At the end of the step, the program checks
whether a chain X appeared at least twice. If this occurred, a variable
chainXParallelism is set equal to the number of chains X that
have been built. Subsequently, these variables are averaged over all chains in
order to yield a degreeOfParallelism. This
degreeOfParallelism is added to a summedDegreeOfParallelism.
Finally, at the end of each year parallelism is obtained by dividing
summedDegreeOfParallelism by the number of steps in that year.
- 5.7
- Figure 8
depicts variability and parallelism calculated by the 1:1 model and averaged
over ten runs. Parameters are the variance of the normal distribution that
regulates the movements of traders of finished products, their watching range,
and the size of the world where firms move.
|
Figure 8. Variability and parallelism averaged over ten runs.
Scale of the simulations: 1:1. Variance of the distribution that
regulates the movements of traders of finished products: 10.0. Watching
range of traders of finished products: 10x10 pixels. World size: 500x600
pixels. |
- 5.8
- In figure 8 we
see variability increasing continuously from the end of the 1950s, when the
Prato industrial district began to expand, to the end of the 1970s, shortly
before the crisis began. In contrast, parallelism was very low until mid
1970s, when it started to increase very rapidly. Since the early 1980s,
parallelism is increasing and variability is decreasing.
- 5.9
- Thus, it appears that the Golden Age of the 1960s and 1970s corresponds to
a combination of high variability and low parallelism. Apparently, the Golden
Age was characterised by extremely frequent exchange of the firms contracted
by middlemen, probably reflecting harsh price competition, together with a
high differentiation of production chains, indicating that large, integrated
firms had a hard time to carry out the same jobs.
- 5.10
- Since the 1980s Prato has exhibited slightly decreasing variability and
ever increasing parallelism. Thus, it appears that business relations are
becoming a slightly more stable and also that more and more middlemen are
doing the same thing at a time, suggesting that industry concentration should
take place. It actually did, as from figure 2 it is evident that
in the 1990s the number of plants is decreasing although occupation is stable.
- 5.11
- However, figure 8 is not informative
with regard to the recovery of the 1990s. In fact, no divide is visible
between the late 1980s and the early 1990s.
- 5.12
- The shift from price flexibility to feature flexibility is not captured by
the above curves because they do not distinguish among contributions by
different types of firms. Feature flexibility is not attained uniformly along
the production process, but rather at the very end. The earlier stages of the
production process remained largely unaffected by the historical shift from a
competitive advantage based on low prices to a competitive advantage based on
fabric variety.
- 5.13
- Thus, finishers are the natural candidates for highlighting feature
flexibility. Finding natural representatives of a behaviour based on price
flexibility is less easy, both because on early links the 11 production chains
differ from one another and because in recent years many early stages of the
production process have been moved abroad. Possibly, weavers are the best
candidates, both because they are in the middle of production chains and
because weaving technology is particularly simple to acquire so that
traditionally there are many weavers, each of which is very small.
- 5.14
- Let us introduce two other indicators: finishers' mobility and weavers'
mobility. These indicators refer to particular finishers (weavers) included in
the production chains built by a particular middleman over time steps,
regardless of chain types.
- 5.15
- Finishers' mobility and weavers' mobility are computed as follows.
Firstly, persistence is calculated. This is the number of times that
each particular finisher (weaver) has been attached to the same side of the
same middleman. It is calculated over blocks of one thousand chains built
during one year, except for the last block of each year. Block values are
averaged in order to obtain yearly values denoted
summedFinisherPersistence and summedWeaverPersistence,
respectively. Finally, mobility is calculated as one minus the ratio of
persistence to the number of chains that have been built in a year.
- 5.16
- The higher the mobility of a firm, the higher the flexibility that it
provides. Thus, if we assume that weavers mainly provide price flexibility and
finishers mainly provide feature flexibility, we can observe the evolution of
the relative importance of these two factors. Figure 9 plots finishers'
mobility and weavers' mobility calculated by the 1:1 model and averaged over
ten runs.
|
Figure 9. Mobility of Finishers and Weavers averaged over ten
runs. Scale of the simulations: 1:1. Variance of the distribution that
regulates the movements of traders of finished products: 10.0. Watching
range of traders of finished products: 10x10 pixels. World size: 500x600
pixels. |
- 5.17
- In figure 9 we see that finishers' mobility and weavers' mobility were
both very low when the district was in its infancy, meaning that there was
little flexibility of any kind. The Golden Age of the 1960s and 1970s was
characterised by high weavers' mobility and low finishers' mobility,
indicating that the district was relying on price flexibility alone. However,
the crisis decade of the 1980s already shows the seeds of the recovery of the
1990s, since finishers' mobility was slowly increasing. Finally, at the
beginning of the 1990s finishers' mobility approached weavers' mobility,
meaning that feature flexibility finally became just as important as price
flexibility. Notably, price flexibility did not decrease in the 1980s and
1990s. Eventually, it increased a little, possibly because of massive
clandestine immigration.
- 5.18
- Interestingly, figure 9 does not show any sharp divide between the crisis
of the 1980s and the recovery of the 1990s. Possibly, interviews concerning
profits and expectations (Balestri and
Toccafondi 1994, Balestri and
Toccafondi 1995) show a sharper discontinuity than data on the number of
firms, simply because a long time is needed in order for unprofitable,
traditionally managed family firms to disappear from the market. Possibly, an
economy where unprofitable firms immediately go bankrupt had experienced a
sharper crisis and an earlier recovery.
- 5.19
- The curves illustrated in figures 8 and 9 seem to be quite
robust with respect to parameter values. In order to evaluate the sensitivity
of the model to the variance of the distribution that regulates movements of
the traders of finished products, to the watching range of the traders of
finished products and to the size of the world where firms move, six series of
five runs have been carried out. In these series, the above three parameters
were either increased or decreased by 10%. Subsequently, for each parameter
value the average of the five runs was compared with the average of five runs
carried out with the base parameter values. Comparison was made by computing
the average percentage of the absolute difference between a curve resulting
from new parameter values and the corresponding curve resulting from base
parameter values. In order to assess the role of chance differences, a similar
comparison was made between two curves resulting from the average of two
series of five runs with base parameters values. Table 1 illustrates the
results.
|
Table 1. Indices of the impact of parameters
variations on model outcomes. Given a curve {xi} obtained by
averaging five runs with base parameters values and a curve
{yi} obtained by averaging five runs with modified parameters
values, the index is the average per cent of
|yi-xi|/xi. In the case of the last
column, the two series have been obtained by averaging two different
series of five runs with base values |
|
|
Variance +10% |
Variance –10% |
Watching Range +10% |
Watching Range -10% |
World Size +10% |
World Size -10% |
Base Values |
Variability |
0.035 % |
0.030 % |
0.087 % |
0.078 % |
0.055 % |
0.053 % |
0.035 % |
Parallelism |
0.177 % |
0.152 % |
0.369 % |
0.172 % |
0.136 % |
0.217 % |
0.155 % |
Finishers Mobility |
0.046 % |
0.032 % |
0.083 % |
0.116 % |
0.050 % |
0.052 % |
0.035 % |
Weavers Mobility |
0.027 % |
0.022 % |
0.086 % |
0.092 % |
0.047 % |
0.049 % |
0.024 %
|
|
- 5.20
- On the whole, the model appears to be very robust with respect to 10%
variations of all three parameters. In particular, a 10% variation of variance
appears not to have any impact beyond the difference that can be expected
between any two series of five runs with base values of all parameters. The
model is more sensitive to variations of the watching range of traders of
finished products as well as to variations of world size, but still to a very
limited extent. Among the curves, parallelism is the one that is most
sensitive to parameter variations, possibly because it often takes very low
values.
- 5.21
- Model scale is not really a parameter, but rather a modelling strategy.
Its effect is interesting because it shows whether large agent-based models
are worth doing. Figures 10 and 11 compare the 1:1 model with the 1:10 model
for variability and parallelism, finishers' mobility and weavers' mobility,
respectively.
|
Figure 10. Variability and parallelism for the 1:1 model and
the 1:10 model, averaged over ten runs |
|
Figure 11. finishers' mobility and weavers' mobility for the
1:1 model and the 1:10 model, averaged over ten runs
|
- 5.22
- In figure 10 we can see that both variability and parallelism in the 1:10
model are delayed with respect to variability and parallelism in the 1:1
model, but also that in the 1:10 model variability increases more steeply than
in the 1:1 model. Thus, the 1:10 model does not show a long "Golden Age"
period of high variability and low parallelism, not even a delayed one. In
figure 11 we can see that finishers' mobility and weavers' mobility in the
1:10 model are not delayed compared with the 1:1 model, but they behave very
differently in the final part of the simulation. Apparently, the 1:10 model is
not able to capture the slight but continuous increase of price flexibility
that took place in the 1980s and 1990s. Thus, it appears that working with
real sizes is crucial for empirical agent-based models.
Concluding Remarks
- 6.1
- This research was initiated by a suggestion of an economist to a
physicist, that industrial districts could possibly be studied as
self-organising systems. Ant-hills are a common metaphor for this kind of
models, since the behaviour of an ant-hill is far more complex than the
behaviour of any single ant. The idea was that, in some sense, an industrial
district works like an ant-hill.
- 6.2
- This idea had to be qualified in the course of the investigation, because
the Pratese district appeared to have a structure of its own, centred around
the figure of middlemen. As far as it concerns technology and aesthetical
novelties, Prato is a self-organising system. However, to the extent that
production is organised by middlemen, it is not self-organised. Essentially,
self-organisation requires equal distribution of capabilities and power among
reactive but simple components that establish a number of links with one
another. This is not the case of Prato, since middlemen have entrepreneurial
capabilities and acquaintances that other agents lack.
- 6.3
- Possibly, we are bumping into a kind of general principle. The above
analysis may suggest that the more intelligent the components, the less
intelligent the whole. Do human societies exhibit a macroscopic intelligence
of which we are unaware, just like neurones are unaware of the brain? If a
little experience with a textile industrial district can be extrapolated to
the whole of human society, the answer is "No". The human-hill may be less
intelligent than the ant-hill.
Acknowledgements
-
- This study is at odds with prevailing literature on Italian industrial
districts, particularly in so far as it considers the importance of
clandestine immigrants but also with respect to the role of middlemen. As
such, it raised criticisms, enthusiastic comments and surprised remarks. Since
all of them concurred to improve my paper, I am equally grateful to Peter
Allen, Tito Arecchi, Alberto Baccini, Harald Bathelt, Marco Bellandi, Fiorenza
Belussi, Lucio Biggiero, Gabi Dei Ottati, Paolo Giaccaria, Robert Hassink,
Mauro Lombardi, Peter Maskell, Bart Nooteboom, Päivi Oinas, Antonio Politi,
Fabio Sforzi, Flaminio Squazzoni, Deborah Tappi, Michael Taylor, Eirik Vatne,
Alessandro Vercelli, Bauke Visser, Sieglinde Walter and Jici Wang.
Furthermore, special thanks are due to Gianluigi Ferraris and Matteo Morini
who provided patient and continuous help in writing the simulation program,
Luciana Lazzeretti and Dimitri Storai who assembled a valuable database,
Andrea Balestri of Unione Industriale Pratese who provided information
on fabric variety, and particularly to Serafino Romeo of Pratese
Caritas, who engaged in a quest for rare and valuable data. Finally, it is
hard to say how much I feel indebted to the continuous help, assistance and,
most importantly, encouragement and esteem of Pietro Terna, who sacrificed the
honors of congress limelights in order to defend an uncomfortable paper.
Notes
- 1 In Pratese jargon these are the
contoterzisti, meaning literally "workers for a third party" because
they do not sell their products to the person who ordered them in the first
place. Workers on contract, we would say.
2 In this case, Pratese jargon employs the
specific word impannatori. It derives from panno, which means
"cloth".
References
-
- AIAZZI S, Baussola M, Corsini V, Ganugi P and
Langianni S (1997) Il Sistema Prato: fattori di competitività. Prato:
Provincia di Prato, Quaderni del Sistema Informativo dell'Economia e del
Lavoro 2/1.
AMIN A and Robins K (1990) "Industrial Districts and
Regional Development: Limits and Possibilities". In Pyke F, Becattini G and
Sengenberger W (Eds.), Industrial Districts and Inter-Firm Cooperation in
Italy, Geneva: International Institute for Labour Studies.
AMIN A and Thrift N (1992) Neo-Marshallian Nodes in
Global Networks. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research,
vol. 16, pp. 571-587.
AVIGDOR E (1961) L'industria tessile a
Prato. Milano: Feltrinelli.
BACCINI A, Castellucci L, Mori P A and Vasta M
(2001) Rapporto sul Lavoro Sommerso in Toscana. Mimeo.
BALDINI F and Tesi G (1996) Prato Quality.
Prato: Centro Qualità Tessile.
BALESTRI A (2000) Private communication.
BALESTRI A and Toccafondi D (1991) Opinioni dei
Clienti. Prato: PratoFutura.
BALESTRI A and Toccafondi D (1994) Imprenditori
e Distretti Industriali. Prato: PratoFutura.
BALESTRI A and Toccafondi D (1995) Imprese e
Distretti Industriali, Economia & Management, No. 6, November, pp.
68-76.
BECATTINI G (1969) "Lo Sviluppo Economico della
Toscana, un'ipotesi di lavoro". Reprinted in Becattini G (Ed.) (1999)
L'Industrializzazione Leggera della Toscana. Ricerca sul campo e confronto
di idee, Milano: Angeli.
BECATTINI G (1975) "Lo Sviluppo Economico della
Toscana, con particolare riguardo all'industrializzazione leggera ". Reprinted
in Becattini G (Ed.) (1999) L'Industrializzazione Leggera della Toscana.
Ricerca sul campo e confronto di idee, Milano: Angeli.
BERTINI S and Forlai L (1989) Prospettive del
conto terzismo nel quadro dell'evoluzione del modello Pratese. Bologna:
NOMISMA.
BIGGIERO L (2001) Self-Organizing Processes in
Building Entrepreneurial Networks: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation.
Human Systems Management, forthcoming.
BONAFE' P, Giusti G, Limberti S, Ponzecchi C,
Romagnoli A M and Terenzi D (1999) Nobilitazione Tessile. Manuale per la
formazione degli operatori". Prato: Regione Toscana.
CARITAS (2001) Caritas Diocesana di Prato.
Private communication.
CIAPPEI C and Neri A (1998) Il rapporto
cliente-fornitore nello sviluppo produttivo dei lanifici Pratesi. Padova:
CEDAM.
CIONI E (1997) "Lo Sviluppo del Lavoro Autonomo a
Prato nel Secondo Dopoguerra (1945-1952)". In Becattini G and Braudel F
(Eds.), Prato, Storia di una Città, vol.4: Il Distretto Industriale,
Prato: Comune di Prato - Le Monnier.
DE CECCO M (2000) L'Economia di Lucignolo. Roma:
Donzelli Editore.
GRANDINETTI R and Rullani E (1994) Sunk
Internationalisation: Small Firms and Global Knowledge. Revue d'économie
industrielle, No. 67, 1st trimester.
GRAY M, Golob E, Markusen A and Park S O (1998) New
Industrial Cities? The Four Faces of Silicon Valley. Review of Radical
Political Economics, vol. 30, pp. 1-28.
HAKEN H (1983) Synergetics: An Introduction.
Berlin: Springer Verlag.
HAKEN H (1987) Advanced Synergetics. Berlin:
Springer Verlag.
HARRISON B (1994) Lean and Mean. New York:
Basic Books.
ISTAT (1951) III Censimento Generale
dell'Industria e del Commercio. Roma: ISTAT.
ISTAT (1961) IV Censimento Generale dell'Industria
e del Commercio. Roma: ISTAT.
ISTAT (1971) V Censimento Generale dell'Industria
e del Commercio. Roma: ISTAT.
ISTAT (1981) VI Censimento Generale
dell'Industria, del Commercio, dei Servizi e dell'Artigianato. Roma:
ISTAT.
ISTAT (1990-1994) Popolazione e Movimento
Anagrafico dei Comuni. Roma: ISTAT.
ISTAT (1991) VII Censimento Generale
dell'Industria e dei Servizi. Roma: ISTAT.
ISTAT (1996) Censimento Intermedio dell'Industria
e dei Servizi. Roma: ISTAT.
ISTAT (2000) La Presenza Straniera in Italia:
caratteristiche demografiche. Roma: ISTAT.
KOHONEN T (1989) Self-Organisation and
Associative Memory. Berlin: Springer Verlag.
LANE D and Maxfield R (1996) Strategy under
Complexity: Fostering Generative Relationships. Long Range Planning,
vol. 29, No. 2, pp. 215-231.
LAZERSON M H and Lorenzoni G (1999) The Firms that
Feed Industrial Districts: A Return to the Italian Source. Industrial and
Corporate Change, vol. 8, pp. 235-266.
LAZZERETTI L and Storai D (1999) Il distretto
come comunita' di popolazioni organizzative. Prato: IRIS.
LOMBARDI M (2000) The Evolution of Local
Production Systems: the emergence of the "invisible mind" and the evolutionary
pressures towards more visible "minds". Paper presented at the Regional
Enterprise Network Conference, Prague, 22-23 October.
LOMBARDI M (2001) "Cognitive equilibria,
efficiency, and discontinuities in the evolution of Local Production Systems".
In Belussi, F., Gottardi, G. and Rullani, E. (Eds.) Knowledge creation,
learning, and variety of institutional arrangements, forthcoming.
MARSHALL A (1920) Principles of Economics.
London: MacMillan.
MASKELL P (2001) Towards a Knowledge-Based Theory
of the Geographical Cluster. Submitted to Industrial and Corporate
Change.
NICOLIS G and Prigogine I (1977)
Self-Organisation in Nonequilibrium Systems. New York: Wiley.
NICOLIS, G. and Prigogine, I. (1989) Exploring
Complexity. New York: W.H. Freeman and Company.
NUTI F and Cainelli G (1996) Changing Directions in
Italy's Manufacturing Industrial Districts. Journal of Industry
Studies, vol. 3, No. 2, pp. 105-118.
PIETROBELLI C (1998) The Socio-Economic
Foundations of Competitiveness: An Econometric Analysis of Italian Industrial
Districts. Industry and Innovation, vol. 5, pp. 139-155.
RABELLOTTI R and Schmitz H (1999) The Internal
Heterogeneity of Industrial Districts in Italy, Brazil and Mexico. Regional
Studies, vol. 33, pp. 97-108.
ROSEN R (1991) Life Itself. New York: Columbia
University Press.
RULLANI E (1993) "Networks and
Internationalization: Managing Complexity Through Knowledge". In Zan L, Zambon
S and Pettigrew A M (Eds.) Perspectives on Strategic Change, Dordrecht:
Kluwer.
SCOTT A J (1992) The Role of Large Prodcers in
Industrial Districts: A Case Study of High Technology Systems Houses in
Southern California. Regional Studies, vol. 26, pp. 265-275.
VARELA F J (1979) Principles of Biological
Autonomy. New York: Elsevier North Holland.
VON FOERSTER H (1982) Observing Systems.
Seaside: InterSystems.
WANG J, Zhu H and Tong X (2001) Districtization in
the Zhejiang Province of China with Reference to Datang Socks/Stockings
Industrial District. Paper presented at the Conference of the IGU
Commission on the Dynamics of Economic Spaces, Turin, Italy, July 9-14.
Return to
Contents of this issue
©
Copyright Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation,
[2001]